What is LDV ?

Who benefits from LDV?

LDV benefits all participants in the securities finance industry.  Lenders are better able to exercise their corporate governance responsibilities and, since lenders recall fewer loans, overall securities lending volume and revenue increase.  Loan, borrow, and collateral portfolios are more stable, allowing agents and brokers to more effectively manage investment, counterparty, and operational risks.  Corporate issuers receive more proxy votes from long-term investors, allowing them to reach quorum more quickly and at lower cost, and counterbalance votes of short-term activists.  Higher loan volumes also improve financial market liquidity and price discovery.

 

What is Lender-Directed Voting, or LDV?

LDV is a new process that matches securities lenders' loaned shares to broker securities that would otherwise go unvoted, enabling lenders to direct proxies without recalling loans.  It substantially improves existing market practices, which require lenders to recall loan in order to vote proxies.  Recalls are inefficient in that they reduce overall lending and borrowing revenue, and create instability in loan, borrow, and collateral portfolios. 

Why haven't lenders voted on loaned shares in the past?

Historically, institutional securities lenders had to forgo voting rights on loaned shares because there was no mechanism to vote without recalls.  Recent technology and transparency improvements in securities finance markets, however, enable loaned shares to be matched with broker shares that would otherwise go unvoted.  In particular, the Agent Lender Disclosure Initiative made apparent the direct counterparty relationship between lenders and broker-borrowers and provided brokers with detailed loan data necessary to include lenders in their proxy allocation routines.

Are there enough unvoted shares to cover lender voting interest?

Approximately 60 billion U.S. equities go unvoted each year[1], while roughly 15 billion shares are on loan[2], suggesting that sufficient votes could be available to meet lender vote demand.  However, it is unlikely that lender voting interest will be fully covered for all issues, such as those with particularly contentious proxy events or that are hard-to-borrow in securities lending markets. 


[1] www.broadridge.com/investor–communications /us/Broadridge_Proxy_Stats_2010.pdf
[2] Data from RMA securities lending composite, assuming $20 average stock price

Does the broker have the lender’s shares on the proxy record date?

1.  U.S. Federal Reserve Regulation T (“Reg T”) defines the permitted purposes for the extension of credit in the borrowing and lending of securities. In general, all of these purposes involve settling trades through re-delivery of the borrowed securities. Most often, the broker’s need to borrow has arisen after failing to receive securities required for an impending trade settlement, either as the result of an operational breakdown or after a short sale.

2.  Given the broker-borrower’s mandatory compliance with Reg T, it can be argued that borrowed shares, which are re-delivered in the settlement of a trade, are not available on the broker’s books (as a technical matter, the position would be held at DTCC) in order to earn voting rights on the proxy record date. However, this argument would only be true per se if the settlement took place on the proxy record date, because an analysis of the ongoing process reveals that the proxy votes, not just the entitled shares, are properly treated as fully fungible on the broker-borrower’s books.

3.  Reg T does not require that the borrowed shares be returned to the original lender when a subsequent receipt of securities is used to offset the original failure-to-receive. At that point, the borrower can certainly return the securities to the original lender. Yet, an active borrower can also compliantly decide to close a loan of the same securities with a different institutional lender whose terms may have become less attractive or from another broker-dealer lender who may be viewed as more likely to recall shares at an inconvenient time in the future, especially if the shares were borrowed for an ongoing short position. Still another reason may exist to hold the securities if the broker considers the return on its cash collateral, received through a rebate from the lender, to be very attractive compared with other investment options. In all those cases, as well as for actively traded issues where there may be a high risk of ongoing settlement failures, the broker can simply keep the newly-received shares in its inventory, balanced against its obligation to the lender.

4. As a result of efficient management of its settlement obligations, a broker – perhaps all brokers – may well have borrowed positions on their books on proxy record dates. The brokers would have gained the right to assign proxies or even to vote at the next corporate meeting as a direct result of the original loans from institutional lenders. In effect, the proxies are fungible on the brokers’ books, along with the borrowed shares themselves subject, of course, to an equitable assignment of proxy rights in compliance with stock exchange rules. Yet, brokers are not expressly permitted to assign proxies to their institutional lenders. At this point, the Lender Directed Voting (“LDV”) argument gains relevance and substance.

5. As noted, in addition to holding the shares cum voting rights, the broker also retains an obligation to its original lender. Indeed, one could argue that an institutional lender's ownership rights are stronger than those of other “beneficial owners” to whom the broker owes shares in the same securities. That is partly due to the distinction that can be drawn between the institutional lenders, who do not receive proxy assignments, and the broker’s own margin customers and hedge fund clients, who do receive proxy assignments. The distinction resides in the timeline of their property rights: the former owned the shares fully prior to lending them to the broker, while the latter required broker-financing in order to acquire their positions. Although we have seen that the institution’s shares may now be on the broker’s books, it is very likely that the financing customers’ shares are out on loan, i.e., hypothecated as collateral to source the broker’s own funding needs. And, in such cases, those positions are truly not in the brokers’ DTC account, although the brokers may well be assigning proxy rights to their accountholders. One can ably argue that those proxies would more equitably be assigned to the institutional lenders.

How can lenders instruct broker shares?

Brokers administer proxy allocation routines to distribute proxies to their customers.  Since broker shares are held in fungible bulk and lenders have beneficial ownership to loaned shares, brokers can include lenders in their allocation routines.  After brokers allocate proxies to lenders, standard proxy processes are followed to garner and submit voting instructions and submit them to corporate issuers.  For example, proxies are assigned to Broadridge accounts designated for the lenders, then are instructed by lenders or ISS on the lenders' behalf.

Could lenders also instruct custodians' unvoted shares?

Regulatory and operational considerations may pose challenges to matching custodians' unvoted shares with lenders’ loan positions.  In particular, custodian shares are not held in fungible bulk, as are broker shares, which presents difficulties when considering custodial allocation of proxies across lender accounts. Furthermore, custodians are not counterparties on loans, so the lenders are not beneficial owners to any of the custodians’ unvoted shares.

Does LDV contribute to “over-reporting,” since lenders’ shares were delivered to new buyers who now have the associated voting rights?

Existing proxy reconciliation processes are sufficient to address any potential "over-reporting" issues.  For example, brokers already use post-reconciliation processes to mitigate the risk of over-reporting that may arise from assigning proxies to margin customers whose shares may have been loaned or rehypothecated.

How do brokers decide which lender(s) are assigned proxies?

Beneficial owners and regulators have expressed concerns about voting opportunities being directed to preferred lenders or leveraged for beneficial loan terms.  In the same way that agent lending queues are designed so that lenders get equitable access to borrower demand, brokers need pre-defined and algorithmic “proxy queues” to ensure equitable assignment of voting opportunities.  Furthermore, on-going auditing and validation of proxy assignments may be needed to ensure against development of a “market for votes.” 

What if proxies are not available from a lender's borrower, but are from another broker?

Reallocation of the loans to brokers with available proxies would increase overall lender voting opportunities.  However, numerous other loan factors would need to be taken into account, such as counterparty risk assessments and credit limits, loan prices, and collateral types and quantity.  Considering these factors, loan reallocations may not be in the overall best interest of lenders and borrowers, and will have to be considered on a case-by-case basis.

How can lenders know, before record date, how many proxies they will be assigned?

To the extent that lenders receive proxies through LDV, they will not have to recall loans to regain voting rights.  However, broker holdings change daily and varying numbers of investors vote, so the number of proxies that can be assigned to lenders cannot be known with certainty until just before the meeting date, which is typically two months after lenders must make record date recall decisions.   The number of available proxies must therefore be forecasted, taking into account factors such as each broker's customer base, the scarcity of shares in the securities lending market, and the expected materiality of proxy ballot items.

Corporate Governance Blog

Monday, October 25, 2021

Assembling the Market Posse

The Case for a Cross-Border Stock Loan Registry, Part I


Author: Ed Blount

We’ve all been there, having drinks after work with an important client visiting from overseas. My most memorable time was at the very beginning of my career on Wall Street. The client was a trader from the South African branch of Jos. Sebag & Co., a London firm more than 100 years old when he and I met in 1975 at the upscale bar, Michael II. The firm and the restaurant have long since vanished, but at the time Sebag was the most active account for First National City Bank’s (FNCB) American Depositary Receipt (ADR) business. The firm was far more active than Merrill Lynch, Goldman Sachs, or any other cross-border trading outfit. Most of the trades were for the issuance of ADRs in South African mining stocks, such as Anglo-American Gold.

“How is it that you are so active?”, I remember asking, naturally enough (I thought). After all, as the ADR global operations head in FNCB’s 111 Wall Street back office, I was in the best position to see their issuance volumes.

“Most of my clients are plantation owners,” he answered, “who are funding the purchase of weapons to protect their farms and families after the end of Apartheid.”

We only learned their motives by accident.

He went on to explain how his customers bought stocks for deposit in our local FNCB Johannesburg sub-custodian. Their banque wires directed our issuance of ADRs for the benefit of an American broker’s account in DTC, the new central securities depository in New York. After settlement, funds were wired to a Sebag private banking account in London. My trader client told me that the private account was owned by an arms dealer in yet another African country. Sebag issued a draft to the arms dealer's account who then arranged delivery of his products to Sebag’s customers in Rhodesia and South Africa. The transaction chain thus evaded the contemporaneous Anti-Apartheid weapons embargo of the U.S., as well as South Africa’s capital controls on Securities Rand and the UK’s currency restrictions for Sterling Area transfers.

My client, unbeknownst to me, was a gun runner.

Of course, I couldn’t know that until the account info was disclosed to me through the sheer carelessness of trader chutzpah and a third martini. (At the time, internal data sharing at banks was limited by Glass-Steagall era rules that maintained “Chinese Walls” between departmental recordkeeping systems. The laws are gone, too, but many banks still have impenetrable barriers to sharing in their siloed information technology systems.)

Over the years, I’ve seen a lot of interesting trades flow through the cross-border markets. The vast majority are legitimate arbitrage trades, exploiting differences in market intelligence, taxes, forex or other asymmetries. A lot of services have sprung up to support those trades. And a few rogues, like my gun-running client, have also cropped up along the way.

KYC is the sine qua non of finance.

In most cases, it was the insight into certain aspects of their policy tolerances and trading risk profiles (or stupidity) that tripped up the rogues. In the 1970s, “Know Your Customer” (KYC) rules were just starting to insure trading legitimacy through the due diligence standards evolving in developed countries. (The global KYC process is not yet complete: inadequate databases and disclosure rules still hinder enforcement throughout the chain of cross-border transactions.)

It was an early version of the KYC rules that obligated my FNCB superiors to report the chain of transactions to regulators once we learned that the policies and practices of the private Sebag account in FNCB’s London subsidiary allowed for a) offshore settlement in unrestricted currencies and the b) acquisition of weapons stockpiles as alternative assets. (In 1981, the SEC’s censure of Sebag forced the US branch of the firm into liquidation, citing violations of Section 15(c), e.g., undisclosed roguish activities.)

Anti-social trades don't fit with ESG.

Most service providers still don’t have all the information needed to identify antisocial transactions, even though such trades would surely get harsh ratings in today’s market from the ESG consultants. Without knowledge of the controlling policies and practices at the account level, however, the chain of transactions is meaningless to outside auditors, then and now.

The need for policy-level disclosures remains relevant for a new set of anti-social transactions. Once again, regulators are on edge – and scrambling to catch up with the cross-border fraudsters.

Critics question Social Compliance in Cross-Border Financings.

As published online last Friday, a charge of systemic tax fraud has been levied against the ADR and cross-border securities finance markets by a team of investigative reporters, aided by Professor Christoph Spengler from the University of Mannheim in Germany. "Between 2000 and 2020," it is claimed, "an estimated €150 billion in tax revenue was lost across 12 countries due to cum-ex trades, including ADRs."

In general, Spengler and the reporters charge that a network of bad actors has used a variety of dividend capture and swap strategies to evade income taxes or to create claims for repayment of withholding taxes that were never actually paid.

As described, these are essentially legal dividend capture trades that have been turbocharged for illegal purposes and for which the proceeds have been laundered through unsuspecting service providers, e.g., me in 1975. (More on their assumptions later.)

Policy-level data can validate the loan chain.

Critics will challenge Prof. Spengler’s assumptions, but his model will stand until a better one can be used to unweave the tangled web of the loan chain and prove the legitimacy of transactors at both ends. However, better models will need validation algorithms linked to policy-level data, as we learned in 1975, that have never been made available to academics. (Commercial data vendors are blocked from using policy-level data without buy-side releases to their service providers from non-disclosure agreements.) Even the regulators cannot police cross-border loans because the scope of their enforcement authority ends at their borders.

Only the principals can direct their providers to share confidential data. Still, there are many hurdles to overcome before the collective insights of stakeholders can be used to refine risk tolerances and reduce the opportunities for bad actors to game the system. We will call those stakeholders the “Market Posse”.

The Market Posse formed itself during the LTCM crisis.

It is often said that no securities lenders reported credit losses from Lehman’s defaults after its September 2008 bankruptcy. It may be true. That same month, the Risk Management Association published my article praising the stellar risk management skills of a group of creditors who had been able to avoid direct losses when Bear Stearns rolled over six months earlier, and ten years before that, when Long Term Capital Management (LTCM) failed. Those were the schooling events for the counterparty risk managers protecting their clients from Lehman’s possible failure.

Traders in the pits know the body language of desperation. Just so, the Rolodex networks of operations managers can spot signals in trading data to position their defenses against potential events of defaults. Of course, I did not realize while writing in the summer of 2008 that Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. would soon create an even bigger wave in the pond with respect to their counterparty and funding defaults. But I would have expected the same group to again avoid losses. And they did. The managers each shared their suspicions, then lifted their initial margin and counterparty collateral requirements for Lehman, just as they earlier had for both Bear and LTCM in advance of their failures. In April, 2008, the signals from trading desks were saying that, ‘Bear’s two internal hedge fund accounts may be illiquid.’ A passive run-on-the-bank was being engineered because it was well known that the two accounts were paying unusually high fees for credit extensions after counterparties had failed to renew their lines in the funding markets.

Some also suspected that Lehman was hiding leverage by overcollateralizing its repo trades, a notorious strategy called “Repo 105” in the bankruptcy examiner’s report. In effect, the Market Posse roped in the culprits by depleting Lehman’s cash reserves.

In January, 2009, the New York Fed published an explanation by two Yale/NBER economists: "as lenders began to fear for the stability of the banks and the possibility that they might need to seize and sell collateral, the borrowers were forced to raise repo rates and haircuts. Both of these increases occurred in the crisis. In Section IV.C, we find that these increases were correlated with changes in the LIB-OIS (for repo rates) and changes in the volatility of the underlying collateral (for repo haircuts). It is the rise in haircuts that constitutes the run on repo." [1]

Similar metrics will be used to inform today's Market Posse.

Today's Market Posse will have better gear.

In a speech two weeks ago, Natasha Cazenave, newly appointed Director of the European Securities & Markets Authority, called for “firms to take a company-wide, rather than a regime-specific approach to reporting.” That might help to identify rogues at the periphery (and would surely have alerted us in 1975), but Ms. Cazenave went even further. She also endorsed the use of “DLT-based market infrastructures [so that] authorities, like ESMA, could have direct access to the distributed ledgers and could monitor transactions data in real-time. This would reduce the compliance cost for market participants and, at the same time, give more flexibility for the authorities with respect to what data and when they would like to see it.”

The Market Posse could also benefit if those distributed applications also helped lending agents and other service providers to monitor their market exposures, as I explained for the RMA Journal in 2008:

“As useful as credit models and rating systems have become over the last decade or so, the bank still needs its frontline lending officers to understand the markets that their customers depend on for their ability to repay their obligations. One more, underappreciated key to understanding customer markets is a keener appreciation of the wisdom and value of the ‘market posse.’”

A voluntary, encrypted Loan Registry will please regulators -- and ESG lenders.

With the prior approval of beneficial owners, DLT-based infrastructures could allow their regulators and service providers to use a new set of collaborative tools, such as blockchains and smart contracts, to create a cross-border loan registry. That could be used to validate a trader’s counterparty risks as well as a loan’s legitimacy, thereby extending the insights of seasoned risk managers for the benefit of a much wider network of Market Posse members.

Just as in 1998 and 2008, any insight into a counterparty’s need for liquidity, inferred in the fees and rates that its accounts are willing to pay, will be a critical insight. The benefits for a Cross-border Loan Registry could also include a visa as a form of cross-border tax validation, granted for demonstrably benign securities funding trades. (More on that later.) If effective, counterparty risk metrics could reinforce the limited default warranties that lending agent banks provide.  There’s even a chance that the cost of such a service would be borne by the banks as a premium upgrade to their global custodial services. (More later.)   

END PART 1

PART 2: Exposing the Rogue Traders - The Case for a Cross-Border Stock Loan Registry, Part II

 


NOTES:

1. Gary Gorton and Andrew Metrick, "Securitized Banking and the Run on Repo," Jan/Nov, 2009, New York Federal Reserve Bank, p.6

 

Print

Corporate Outreach Milestones

MILESTONES FOR LENDER DIRECTED VOTING

May 8, 2014: Council of Institutional Investors; - CII Elects New Board, Names Jay Chaudhuri Board Chair. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2014-01-31/north-carolina-treasurer-may-cede-pension-control-5-questions.html )

February 2014:  Swiss Minder Initiative implies the value of LDV. http://www.ipe.com/switzerlands-minder-initiative-will-cripple-securities-lending-experts-warn/10000947.article.

January 2014FL SBA begins their SecLending Auction Program with eSecLending.

November 27, 2013 – CSFME staff call with Glass Lewis Chief Operating Officer. He gave his commitment for cooperation and support for LDV, and most importantly, he suggested that perhaps we should discuss with a Broadridge/State Street/Citi the scenario that permits Citi to forward an “Omnibus Ballot” of proxies to State Street, which State Street would then take and assign the proxies to their pension lenders/LDV participants, which would then be incorporated into a single ballot and sent to Broadridge. This eliminates the secondary ballot issue. While this description is oversimplified, Glass Lewis was fairly certain the parties involved could operationally create such a combined ballot. Responding to the question on cost, the Glass Lewis executive stated that the cost depends on the number of voting policies a fund has. Most funds have one policy; therefore, depending on the client, the cost would be $.75 – $2.00 per ballot.

October 21, 2013 – CSFME staff call with ISS Chief Operations Officer. He committed his cooperation and support to advance LDV’s implementation into the markets. He responded to the question about cost: “It depends on the client and the services they use. $6-7 per ballot on average.”

June 25-28, 2013 – CSFME staff attended ICGN Annual Conference in NY, NY. Spoke with executives of CalSTRS; ICGN Chair and Blackrock about LDV.  We received favorable comments and encouragement from each.

June 6, 2013: CSFME meets with Chief Investment Officer for NYC Pension Funds. While very much in favor of the LDV concept, the comments that the NYC Pension Fund Boards are for the most part followers in new initiatives and would prefer a roll-out by other funds first.

April 5, 2013: ‘SEC gives CSFME limited approval for LDV going forward’ providing brokers assign proxies only from their proprietary shares.

March 26, 2013 – CSFME and its legal team presented the case for LDV to SEC Commissioner Dan Gallagher. Present by phone and speaking on behalf of LDV were representatives of FL SBA who spoke about the difficulty of timely recall of shares on loan following release of record date and issues on agenda; and a representative from CalSTRS who spoke about their recall policy affecting income.

March 13, 2013 – CSFME meet staff of Senator Rob Portman and Congressman Steve Stivers of Ohio. These meetings were for the purpose of lining up political support, should the SEC resist the LDV concept. We also met and spoke with CII Deputy Director Amy Borrus for one hour and 15 minutes for a scheduled 30 minute meeting.  She expressed great interest in the value of LDV to long-term beneficial owners.

January 17, 2013 – CSFME conference call with CoPERA Director of Investments.  Among CoPERA’s concerns were: (1) How are agents/brokers notified re: LDV? (2) Who moves or approaches first lender to agent or agent to lender? CSFME responds  that a side letter is needed between lender, agent and broker.

November 8, 2012 – CSFME conference call with Council of Institutional Investors (CII) detailing LDV. Some in attendance were opposed to securities lending because of their desire to vote 100% of recall. This position would be irrelevant giving CalSTRS’ change to policy on proxy recall.

October 24, 2012, 2PM – CSFME presents LDV to Broadridge Institutional Investor Group. At this meeting, a representative of CalSTRS states: “We would view brokers willing to provide proxies more favorably than those who would not.” We were also informed by CalSTRS that they were looking to change their 100% recall policy. A representative of SWIB led a discussion on International Voting Issues, and apparently was chairing 3 meetings to determine the following: 1. who is voting internationally? 2. What are the issues in the international markets? 3. How do we increase and improve international processes?

October 24, 2012, 11AM – EWB/KT conference call with ICGN.  Executives stated that the argument for LDV may not be as strong in a non-record date market, and asked what would be the cost for LDV.  They further stated that they would like to see the U.S. go with LDV first and would need more information and operational detail.

October 13, 2012 email note from Elizabeth Danese Mozely to Broadridge’s Institutional Investor Working Group: “TerriJo Saarela, State of Wisconsin Investment Board, will provide commentary on their fund’s interest in international voting and an update on her participation in the Council of Institutional Investors’ working group on international voting.  Our discussion will include the differences in process for voting abroad, share blocking, attendance at the meeting via proxy or Power of Attorney (POA), best practices available through the various laws and regulations, etc.”

September 18, 2012: CSFME contacts Blackrock/ICGN Chair for a brief on LDV.

August 13, 2012 – CSFME conference call with OTPP.  Discussion of LDV was not timely in that their SecLending Program stopped lending securities through agents in mid-2006. State Street is their custodian and they were using a tri-party repo through Chase to Lehman, until the Lehman collapse. All the assets sat at Chase. It was not clear who had voting rights. At the time of this discussion in August 2012, OTPP was thinking formulating an SLA because they do not have the capacity to lend securities on their own. We have had no discussion with them since.

August 2, 2012 – CSFME contacts Ontario Teachers’ Pension Plan (OTPP) regarding LDV.

March 19, 2012 – CSFME conference call with executive in charge of securities lending for Franklin Templeton

February 22, 2012ICGN sends LDV letter of support to the SEC, signed by Chairman of the ICGN Board of Governors.

September 30, 2011CalSTRS sends LDV letter of support to the SEC, signed by Director of Corporate Governance Anne Sheehan.

July 18, 2011Florida SBA sends LDV letter of support to the SEC, signed by Executive Director and Chief Investment Officer.

November 2011 – CSFME introduces Council of Institutional Investors editor to LDV.

July 5, 2011 – CSFME sends a Comment Letter to the Securities and Exchange Commission regarding LDV.

October 2010 – CSFME releases report: Borrowed Proxy Abuse: Real or Not? This report and the SEC’s Securities Lending and Short Selling Roundtable prompted the question from beneficial owners and regulators regarding the need to recall shares on loan to vote proxies, why can’t lenders receive proxies for shares on loan when we get the dividends? From this question, the idea for Lender Directed Voting was born.

January 2010 – SEC issues rules that brokers no longer have the discretion to vote their customers’ shares held in companies without receiving voting instructions from those customers about how to vote them in an election of directors. http://www.sec.gov/investor/alerts/votingrules2010.htm. The rule, periodically, contributed to the difficulty of corporate meetings attaining a quorum.

Fall 2009/2010 – Four public pension funds join CSFME in Empty Voting studies/LDV initiative; FL SBA, CalSTRS, SWIB and CoPERA.

September 29-30, 2009 - SEC Announces Panelists for Securities Lending and Short Sale Roundtable; http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2009/2009-207.htm